Money As Equity: For An "Accounting View" Of Money
the
issuing states, and are reported as a component of public debt under
their respective national accounting statistics (ESA, 2010). Similarly,
banknotes issued by central banks, and by extension central bank
reserves (which represent the largest share of money base in every
contemporary economy), are considered as liabilities of the issuing
central banks and are accounted for as central bank debt to their
holders.
By Biagio Bossone e Massimo Costa
In
fact, even though the law says that money is “debt”, a correct
application of the general principles of accounting does raise deep
doubts about such a conception of money. Debt typically involves an
obligation between lender and borrower as contracting parties. We wonder
which obligation may fall upon the state from the rights entertained by
the holders of coins, or which obligation may fall upon the central
bank from the rights entertained by the holders of banknotes or by the
banks holding reserves.
We specifically
refer to these three “species” of money because they are all “legal
tender”, that is, in force of a legal power, they absolve their issuers
of any responsibility to convert them into other forms of value. This is
not the case, obviously, for monies that are convertible on demand into
commodities or liabilities issued by third parties (e.g., currencies of
other countries). On the other hand, conversion of reserves into
banknotes does not constitute a central bank’s debt obligation, since it
only gives rise to a substitution of one form of liability for another
that is issued by the same central bank and is not redeemable in any
other form of value produced by third parties.
A similar question
can be asked with respect to the money issued by commercial banks in the
form of sight deposits, inasmuch as this money plays a similar role to
that of legal tender in almost all bank-customer relations (excluding
interbank obligations, which require central bank money as settlement
asset).[1]
We shall return to this type of money later on in the article. Below we
focus on legal tender monies issued by the state or the central bank.
Legal tender: if it is not debt, what else is it?
In the old days,
local sovereigns guaranteed that the coins they issued contained a
specific amount of precious metal (silver or gold).[2]
Still in those days, banknotes gave their holders the right to claim
for their conversion into silver or gold coins. To be able to match
those claims, sovereigns needed to hold adequate volumes of metal
reserves. The same kind of obligation committed central banks with
respect to their reserve liabilities issued to commercial banks.
Therefore, all three species of money gave origin to true debt
obligations that were legally binding on their issuers and could be
triggered on demand by their holders at any point in time.
But
this was the past. Today, convertibility has all but disappeared for
each of the three money species under discussion. Coins have lost most
of their relevance and have been largely replaced by paper money.
Convertibility of banknotes has been suspended long ago, and the
abandonment of the gold-exchange standard, about half a century ago,
marked the definitive demise of “debt” banknotes even at the
international level. Finally, the reserve deposits held by commercial
banks and national treasuries at central banks are today delinked from
any conversion obligation into commodities or third-party liabilities
(except where the central bank adheres to fixed exchange rate
arrangements, the economy is dollarized, or the country is under a
currency board regime).
Therefore, although
for legacy reasons, or simply due to conventional choice, money is
still allocated as debt in public finance statistics and central bank
financial statements, it is not debt in the sense of carrying
obligations that imply creditor rights.[3] Rather, it represents equity for the issuer and, as such, it implies ownership rights.
Issuing legal tender involves a sui generis transaction whereby the money is sold in exchange for other assets.[4] The proceeds from this sale represent a form of income, specifically a ‘revenue income’.[5]
Issuing legal tender thus generates revenue income to the issuer. Under
current accounting practices, this income is (incorrectly) unreported
in the income statement of the central bank, and is instead
(incorrectly) set aside under the central bank’s ‘liabilities’.
When money is
issued by a public entity, the associated revenue income accrues to the
entity’s owners: the citizens. When, on the other hand, money is issued
by a privately owned central bank, the revenue income accrues to the
central bank’s private owners. If it is not distributed to the owners,
the revenue income goes into retained earnings and becomes equity.
The assimilation of
money to equity requires going beyond the conventional distinction
between equity and liabilities, as is typically applied to investigate
the nature of financial instruments.[6]
A correct application of the principles of general accounting
recognizes that money accepted as legal tender is not a financial
instrument as defined by the international accounting standards, and
therefore cannot be debt. IAS 32 defines a ‘financial instrument’ as “a
contract that gives rise to a financial asset of one entity and a
financial liability or equity instrument of another entity”, and defines
an ‘equity instrument’ as “any contract that evidences a residual
interest in the assets of an entity after deducting all of its
liabilities” (par. 11). Under these definitions, legal tender money is
not a financial instrument, and it is neither ‘credit’ for its holder
nor ‘debt’ for its
issuer. Instead, it is net wealth for the holder and net worth (equity) for the issuer.
issuer. Instead, it is net wealth for the holder and net worth (equity) for the issuer.
Money accounted for
as equity of the issuing entity implies ownership rights. These rights
must not be understood as giving money holders possession over the
entity issuing the money (as shares giving investors ownership of a
company or residual claims on the company’s net assets). Rather, they
are the same as those acquired by consumers purchasing goods by firms,
since selling a commodity that grants specific utility to consumers is
not conceptually dissimilar from selling an instrument that grants its
acquirers a general type of utility – that of settling financial
obligations.[7]
Thus, the ownership
rights attached to money as equity consist of claims on shares of
national wealth that money holders may exercise at any time. Those who
receive money acquire additional and definitive purchasing power on
national wealth. Those issuing money get in exchange a form of gross
revenue that is equal to its nominal value. The revenue income
calculated as the difference between the gross revenue from money
issuance and the cost of producing money is a rent universally known as
‘seigniorage’. This special form of rent can be appropriated exclusively
by those who hold the power to issue money, or are granted such power.
To summarize, our proposed ‘Accounting View’ of money holds that:
·
Money circulating in the economy as legal tender is not a financial
instrument - it is neither credit for the holders nor debt of the issuer
· This money is
sold or lent in exchange for other assets and generates revenue incomes
to the issuer, and should so be reported in the issuer’s balance sheet
· These revenue incomes constitute a special form of rents, called seigniorage, which is are appropriated by the money issuer
· The accumulation
(and non distribution) of revenue incomes thus generated constitute the
equity of the issuer, and should be recorded as such in the issuer’s
balance sheet
· This equity grants the holders of money ownership rights in the form of purchasing power over shares of the national wealth.
Implications
Two main implications follow.
First, rents from
seigniorage are systematically concealed, and seigniorage revenue is not
allocated to the income statement (where it naturally belongs) and is
instead recorded on the liabilities side of the balance sheet, thus
originating outright false accounting. Furthermore, primary seigniorage
should be distinguished from “secondary” seigniorage, which derives from
the interest income received on the money that is issued and lent out.
The state does not receive any secondary seigniorage from coins (they
are not lent), while central banks receive seigniorage from both
banknote and reserve issuances but account only for the former and not
for the latter.
Second, the same
process that has led coins and then paper money and eventually central
bank reserves to become legal tender partly extends as well to
commercial bank money (i.e., sight deposits), which all of us use daily
for transactions. In this case, although such money bears for the
issuing banks the obligation to convert it into cash (on demand by
depositors) or central bank reserves (for interbank settlements), its
assimilation to legal tender grows to the extent that modern payment
systems reduce the use of cash and economize on the use of central bank
reserves.[8]
An important (and
still unrecognized) consequence of this assimilation is that banks’
deposit liabilities, recorded as banks’ ‘debts’ toward customers,
generate revenues for the issuing banks – much as banknotes and reserves
do for the central banks issuing them.[9]
Therefore, with reduction of cash usage and growing scale economies in
the use of central bank reserves, increasing rents are appropriated by
the (largely privately owned) commercial banking sectors of our
economies.
Conclusion
The foregoing
discussion offers a broad outline of a new approach that we refer to as
the “Accounting View” of legal tender money. The proposed new approach
calls for understanding money by correctly applying to it the principles
of general accounting. We think it will be important to further deepen
the study of the implications of the new approach.
From a very
preliminary analysis, a most important one is the current
under-appreciation of the seigniorage extracted by money issuers. It
will be necessary to identify and to estimate such seigniorage, the
share of seigniorage that is returned to its legitimate “owners” (i.e.,
the citizens), and its effects on economic activity, as well as on the
economy’s incentives structure and the distribution of national wealth
across the society.
With
specific reference to public finances, we hope the new approach will
eventually lead to “cleaning up” fiscal budgets and the balance sheet of
central banks from the false accounting practices that derive from
considering legal tender as “debt”. Finally, if money is accounted for
as debt, instead of being considered as equity of the issuing entities
and wealth for the society using it, it inevitably introduces a
deflationary bias in the economy.
References
Bossone, B. (2000),
What Makes Banks Special? A Study of Banking, Finance, and Economic
Development, Policy Research Working Paper No. 2408, World Bank,
Washington, DC.
Bossone, B. (2001), Circuit theory of banking and finance, Journal of Banking and Finance, Vol. 25, Issue 5, vol. 25, Issue
5, 857-890.
5, 857-890.
Bossone, B. (2017), Commercial Bank Seigniorage: A Primer, The World Bank, forthcoming (available in manuscript
from the author on request).
from the author on request).
Costa, M. (2009), Sulla natura contabile delle “passività monetarie” nei bilanci bancari, Quaderni Monografici Rirea, n. 85.
CPSS (2003), The Use of Central Bank Money in Payment Systems, Committee on Payment and Settlement Systems, Bank for
International Settlements.
International Settlements.
Davidson, P. (1972), Money and the Real World, The Economic Journal, Vol. 82, No. 325 (Mar.), 101-115.
ESA (2010), European System of Accounts, Eurostat, European Commission.
Maheswari, S. N. (2013), Principles of Financial Accounting, Vikas Publishing House.
McLeay, M., Radia,
A., and R. Thomas (2014), Money Creation in the Modern Economy, Bank of
England Quarterly Bulletin, 54(1), 14-27.
PWC (2017), Distinguishing liabilities from equity, Price Waterhouse Cooper. [10]
PAAinE (2008), Distinguishing between Liabilities and Equity, Pro-Active Accounting in Europe, Discussion Paper.
Schmidt, M. (2013), Equity and Liabilities – A Discussion of IAS 32 and a Critique of the Classification, Accounting in
Europe, 10 (2), 201-222.
Europe, 10 (2), 201-222.
[1]
In fact, commercial bank money may serve as settlement instrument (and
hence, de facto, as legal tender) for all interbank transactions taking
place across accounts held on the books of the same bank (“on us”
payments). Moreover, many payment systems adopt commercial bank
liabilities as settlement assets (CPSS, 2003).
[2] See Costa (2009) for an analysis of the money liabilities in commercial bank balance sheets.
[3]
ESA (cit.) establishes that "coins are issued by central governments in
the euro area, although, by convention, they are treated as liabilities
of the national central banks which as a counterpart hold a notional
claim on general government” (emphasis added). The expression ‘by
convention’ and the qualification of claims as ‘notional’, especially as
they are used in a regulatory text, betray the lack of foundations
supporting the concept of legal tender as a 'debt' liability of the
issuing entity. We owe this observation to Marco Cattaneo.
[4] The money is sold even when it is exchanged against credit claims under lending contracts.
[5]
Income may take the form of capital income or revenue income. The
former does not relate to running a business, while the latter arises
from running business activities (Maheshwari, 2013).
[6] See, for instance, Schmidt (2013), PAAinE (2008), and PWC (2017).
[7]
However, the similarity between money and goods in providing utility to
holders and consumers, respectively, does not eliminate the unique
features of money, such as its zero (or negligible) elasticity of
production and its zero (or negligible) elasticity of substitution
(Davidson, 1972).
[8]
The very same real-time gross settlement (RTGS) systems, which
typically require the mobilization of large volumes of central bank
reserves, nowadays adopt technologies that permit the use of continuous
(bilateral and/or multilateral) netting of interbank transactions, which
drastically reduce the volume of reserves needed for settlement.
[9]
That commercial banks create money (via their lending activity) is
nowadays been recognized even by mainstream economic theory (McLeay et
al., 2014). The secondary seigniorage that commercial banks extract from
deposit creation derives from the revenue they receive from deposit
issuances and the cost to raise the central bank reserves needed for
settling payments (Bossone 2000, 2001 and 2017). It should be noted that
in order for commercial banks to issue new deposits they do not need to
incur new debts with customers (by accepting new deposits from them).
They do need to raise the central bank reserves necessary to settle the
obligations to other banks deriving from the holders of new deposits
ordering payments. This can be achieved by mobilizing unutilized
reserves, and accepting reserves from incoming payments, by borrowing
reserves from the interbank market or the central bank, and by
attracting reserves through new deposits (from old and/or new clients).
The larger the share of the bank over total interbank payments, and the
higher the efficiency of managing reserves for payment settlements, the
less the reserves needed to support new deposit issuances,, and thus the
larger the seigniorage. All else equal, commercial bank seigniorage
increases when the central banks remunerates the reserves that
commercial banks hold with it.
Nessun commento:
Posta un commento